Regarding Congress' power under the Commerce Clause and with
respect to Category Three Regulation of Local Activities with a
Substantial Economic Effect on Interstate Commerce, I want to be sure
about the scope of Congress' power when they regulate in the aggregate
as distinguished from regulating under a comprehensive regulatory
scheme.
My understanding (Wickard) is that Congress can regulate an
individual instance of economic activity under an aggregation theory.
However, if Congress has enacted a comprehensive regulatory scheme,
Congress has an additional constitutionally permissive reach into
non-economic aspects of the activity that is not available under an
aggregation theory. Is this a correct way to look at it?
Additionally I am unclear if reach into regulating a class of
actvities as in Perez is available under an aggregation theory, or when
there is a comprehensive regulatory scheme, or if it is stands alone?
Answer Number One
Your understanding of the difference between aggregation (adding up all
the small instances of economic activity to show a substantial effect
on interstate commerce) vs. the use of a comprehensive regulatory
scheme (regulating both economic and noneconomic activity because both
are integral parts of a problem that Congress is addressing allowing a
court to characterize the scheme in its entirety as a regulation of
economic activity) is one hundred percent correct.
As to the class of activities theory described in Perez, that's a
harder question to answer. One reason it's harder is that Perez comes
long before Lopez decided that the distinction between economic and
noneconomic activities was relevant. Therefore, Perez wasn't using the
class of activities concept to justify regulating noneconomic
activities. After all, all lending of money is a quintessential
economic activity so that wasn't a problem facing the Court. On the
other hand, it also wasn't using it for aggregation purposes because it
didn't claim that lending money like Perez did, independent of
interstate organized crime, had an effect on interstate commerce. I
think it could have made this argument (as we discussed in class), but
it didn't.
That means it wasn't really using the class of activities concept for
either of the two purposes. However, I think it's closer to the
comprehensive regulatory scheme theory, but not to include some
noneconomic instances of the activity in the regulatory scheme.
Instead, it's to include some instances of the activity that don't have
any proven effect on interstate commerce in the regulatory scheme. In
the opinion, in talking about both Heart of Atlanta Motel v. United
States and Katzenbach v. McClung, both of which the Perez Court says
are cases that relied on the class of activities test, the Court says:
- In emphasis of our position that it was the class of activities
regulated that was the measure, we acknowledged that Congress
appropriately considered the "total incidence" of the practice on
commerce. Where the class of activities is regulated and that class is
within the reach of federal power, the courts have no power "to excise,
as trivial, individual instances" of the class.
The Court is saying that when, in general, most instances of an
activity are tied to interstate commerce (like serving patrons in a
restaurant that buys its food from interstate commerce or providing
lodging for travelers or lending money at extortionate rates), Congress
can regulate all instances of the activity without the need to prove
that any individual instance has a tie to interstate commerce. That
means that the class can include some instances of the activity that
have no effect on interstate commerce, not even a trivial one.
Question Number Two
Regarding the Privileges & Immunities Clause of Article IV, I have
a question concerning the third preliminary hurdle that a challenger
must satisfy. Why have access to private employment opportunities been
found to be fundamental/essential activities protected by Art. 4 Sec.
2.?
Answer Number Two
The purpose of the Privileges & Immunities Clause of Article IV is
similar to the dormant Commerce Clause. It makes sure that economic
opportunities within a state (e.g., selling a product, getting a job)
are available to residents and nonresidents. This supports the idea of
the nation being a single economic unit with states not being able to
erect trade barriers to wall off competition from other states. Both
clauses focus on the private marketplace rather than government
employment and government services. They do this in different ways with
the dormant Commerce Clause having the market participant exception to
protect the state's own participation in the market and the P & I
Clause using the third hurdle as a way of allowing the states to
protect their own activities and resources such as who the states hire
to work for the government and other opportunities such as subsidies
that states make available.
Question Number Three
I see how the undue burden test can be a substitute for strict scrutiny
in abortion cases, but I don't understand its sorting function. I also
don’t understand how the undue burden test can subject regulations that
are relatively minor intrusions to the minimum rationality test. Since
we have discussed abortion and reproductive rights as fundamental
issues, I can't understand why there would be any time where the
minimum scrutiny standard applies. Would you be able to provide a few
examples?
Answer Number Three
The undue burden test focuses exclusively on the impact of the abortion
regulation on the pregnant woman. It has nothing to do with the state
objectives or the relationship between the ends and the means. In that
sense it isn't a traditional standard of review. It is inserted in the
analysis even thought the Court has reaffirmed that the woman has a
fundamental right to choose whether or not to terminate her pregnancy
up to the point of viability. It's principle purpose is to allow the
state to adopt some regulations of abortion that would be
unconstitutional if the Court were to continue to apply the strict
scrutiny standard to all abortion regulations. It does this by dividing
regulations of abortion into 2 categories - regulations that severely
limit a woman's right to terminate a pregnancy (undue burdens) and
regulations that have only a minor impact on the woman's right to
terminate her pregnancy (less than undue burdens). Regulations that
fall into the first category continue to be analyzed under the strict
scrutiny test. Regulations in the second category are essentially
excluded from the category of laws that interfere with a fundamental
right and so they are analyzed under minimum rationality review.
Another way to look at it is that the fundamental right to terminate a
pregnancy has been narrowed so the right only protects against major
intrusions on the right (laws that impose an undue burden), but the
fundamental right does not extend to protecting against minor
intrusions on the right.
As for some examples, less than undue burdens were found in Casey when
the state imposed informed consent requirements, imposed a 24 hour
waiting period between receiving certain information and obtaining an
abortion, and required abortion providers to report information about
abortions they have performed to the state. Having found them to impose
less than an undue burden, they were all upheld. By contrast, the
spousal notification provision was found to impose an undue burden and
was struck down. Right now there are battles in the courts about
requiring that physicians who perform abortions at abortion clinics
have admitting privileges to a local hospital and requiring that women
undergo a sonogram before obtaining an abortion. The constitutionality
of these requirements likely will turn on whether they do or do not
impose an undue burden. If they do, they likely won’t be able to
survive strict scrutiny because they aren’t necessary to protect a
woman’s health. If they don’t, they likely will be able to survive
minimum rationality because there are rational reasons for the
requirements.
Question Number Four
My question concerns the Dormant Commerce Clause and economic
protectionist as not being a legitimate local purpose. I find it very
hard to distinguish when the state is engaging in legitimate purposes
such as health, safety, or consumer protection and when it is acting as
an economic protectionist by benefiting in-state economic interests by
burdening out of state competitors. If would appreciate it if you could
help distinguish this a little bit better.
Answer Number Four
Under dormant Commerce Clause analysis, the challenger can make an
economic protectionism argument if there is any evidence that the
purpose of a state law is to help out some local businesses by gaining
some economic advantage for them at the expense of out-of-state
businesses, or is intended to avoid some economic burden the state
would otherwise bear by shifting that burden to other states, or is
designed to protect the state's economy at the expense of the economies
of other states. In these circumstances, the state will try to defend
against this argument by trying to show it has a legitimate reason for
the law like health, safety, environmental protection, etc.. Most
dormant Commerce Clause questions will suggest some legitimate reason
for the law, but many will also suggest the possibility of economic
protectionism. If you see both, that gives each side an argument. One
reason that it's hard to tell the difference is that health, safety,
environmental protection, etc. often involve saving or spending money.
However, the issue is why was the law enacted. One way to study for
this is to look at prior questions where points were given for economic
protectionism and try and identify what facts could be used to both
make that argument and to refute that argument. I think you'll see a
pattern if you look at a number of such questions.