Answers for Spring Break Exam Review Questions
Note: Some of the material is in the form of a grading sheet for the
exam question and some is in the form of a model answer to the question
and sometimes both are provided. In either case, these are “ideal”
answers and even students who receive an “A” for their answer to a
particular question would not get every single point which is allocated
to a question.
Question One Answer
Adam Audrey (AA) would argue that FCSPA is a violation of the Commerce
Clause in Article I, Section 8 which gives Congress the power to
regulate interstate commerce. Adam would first argue that interfering
with a patient’s decision to have cosmetic surgery is a local activity
and not interstate commerce itself. Therefore, Congress can only
regulate the decision to have cosmetic surgery if it can show that the
decision has a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce.
Moreover, the activity is noneconomic and therefore it must satisfy the
stricter standard found in Lopez and Morrison.
The decision to have cosmetic surgery is a personal decision in which
an individual makes a life altering decision to change their
appearance. This is not an economic activity. While cosmetic surgery is
a commercial enterprise, Congress is not regulating the economic
aspects of that activity, but only the personal decision of the
patient. It is attempting to discourage such surgery on moral and not
economic grounds.
Because it is a noncommercial decision, the government must show there
is a direct and substantial relationship between its effort to
discourage cosmetic surgery and an effect on interstate commerce. It
cannot rely on a series of attenuated links in a chain of reasoning
that link discouraging cosmetic surgery to saving the patient money to
the patient having more money to spend on other consumer goods and
services to patients in the aggregate who are rejected by the Cosmetic
Surgery Approval Panel spending the money they have saved and
stimulating the economy. This is the sort of limitless argument whereby
any activity, in the aggregate, can be linked to interstate commerce.
This is the kind of argument rejected by the Court in Lopez and
Morrison because Congress has no general police power.
In addition to the lack of a direct link to interstate commerce, FCSPA
also lacks other factors that might influence a court to uphold the
legislation. AA would argue the statute does not contain a
jurisdictional element limiting its reach to situations where a
specific link to interstate commerce can be demonstrated such as in the
case of patients who have come from other states to have such surgery.
In addition, while Congress has made some findings those findings are
not determinative and, in addition, the findings only show that there
has been a steep rise in people having plastic surgery. The findings do
not show the connection between the steep rise and a substantial impact
on interstate commerce. While the steep rise in cosmetic surgery has
helped the industry to be more profitable, Congress is not acting to
improve the economic situation of the cosmetic surgery industry. It is
trying to discourage such surgery. Further the area it is regulating,
the doctor/patient relationship, is not one that has been traditionally
regulated by the federal government. State governments are the ones who
license physicians, discipline physicians who commit malpractice and
regulate other areas related to FCSPA. When the federal government
intrudes on
an area of traditional state control, a court is less likely to uphold
the federal action.
Even if the decision to have cosmetic surgery is characterized as an
economic activity, AA will argue in the alternative that the law is
unconstitutional because Congress could not rationally conclude that
such decisions in the aggregate have a substantial economic effect on
interstate commerce. Congress is depressing the market for
cosmetic surgery, but cosmetic surgery is not like wheat or some other
product sold in interstate commerce so decisions about whether to
purchase this medical procedure do not have a substantial economic
effect on interstate commerce. Moreover, such procedures are not
usually covered by health insurance so that eliminating unnecessary
surgeries will not reduce the costs of health insurance, but will only
redirect discretionary spending by consumers to other activities.
This economic effect is not sufficient to justify the federal law under
the Commerce Clause.
By contrast, HHS will argue in defense of FCSPA. First it will argue
that the decision to have cosmetic surgery is an economic activity. The
patient is deciding to purchase a medical service for which the patient
will have to pay a significant amount of money. This is a commercial
exchange and not a noneconomic activity.
Because it is an economic activity, the federal government will only
need to satisfy
the more lenient standard from Wickard v. Filburn and other cases such
as the Heart of Atlanta Motel case. It will
only need to show that Congress could have rationally concluded that
regulating cosmetic surgery will have a substantial economic effect on
interstate commerce in the aggregate. It can show that patients will
not need to take time off from work because of unnecessary surgery,
there will be lower rates of medical malpractice because there will be
fewer surgeries thus avoiding a drain on the economy, and patients will
have more money to spend on other goods and services, thereby
stimulating other more important parts of the U.S. economy. This
satisfies the test used by the Court.
Moreover, HHS argues that even under the stricter test of Lopez used if
the regulated activity is considered to be noncommercial, the law
should be upheld. AA traveled in interstate commerce to seek medical
treatment so there is a direct link between his individual circumstance
and interstate commerce. Moreover, there is a direct and substantial
relationship between the regulated activity, avoiding unnecessary and
expensive surgery, and an economic effect on interstate commerce.
Avoiding patients paying for surgery they may not be able to afford
will avoid a drain on the economy, avoiding potential botched surgeries
will avoid a further drain on the economy and keeping patients from
taking time off from work to recover from surgery will improve worker
productivity and will add more money to the consumer economy. These are
direct effects of FCSPA and should result in the statute being upheld.
Question One Answer Sheet
Federal Cosmetic Surgery Protection Act (40 points)
Congress has power to reg local commerce when it has a subl eco effect
on IC-cat 3(3 pts)____
is CSPA a reg of eco or noneco activity-Lopez vs. Wickard v.
Filburn-identify issue(1)____
argue cosmetic surgery (CS) is an eco activity-profit making, sale of
service(3)____
argue gov’t reg. of decision to get surgery-that’s a personal choice
not eco activity(3)____
if eco-could Cong have rat’ly concluded surgery decision in agg has
subl eco IC effect IC(3)____
big interstate business-patients travel, drugs, implants, etc; but gov
reg
limits surgery-effect of depressing eco, but still eco effect; frees up
$; avoids eco effects of unnec’y/failed CS(6)____
if noneco activity-use Lopez factors to analyze whether w/in scope of
Commerce Power(1)____
jur’l element- no jur’l element-under statute no need to show effect on
IC in indiv case(3)____
some findings made by Congress, but do they show connection between
surgery & IC(3)____
direct & subst’l effect on IC?-AA traveled interst-nexus to IC; CS
is a major eco activity; affects # of CSs; frees up $, but reg. of
decision so long series of links in chain-limitless arg(6)____
aggregate effect on IC or must challenger show affect in each
individual case(3)____
area trad’ly reg’d by states or fed?-no regs on CS; health care-fed’l
role, but also states(2)____
Miscellaneous______________________________________________________(3)____
Question Two Answer Sheet
Louisiana Food Misrepresentation Law (Catfish Labeling) (50 points)
preemption-valid federal labeling law?-is it a constitutional exercise
of the commerce power?(4 pts)____
preemption - express permission to add labeling reqs, but not to
confuse - which is this?(6)____
conflict-is it impossible to comply w/ both - Imported Catfish label
complies with both?(6)____
conflict - undermines purpose of fed’l law? (what is federal purpose
and does state law undermine it?)(5)____
occupation of field-did Congress intend to fully occupy the
field?(4)____
dormant commerce clause - protectionism-evidence of lobbying, but state
purpose(6)____
discrimination against interstate com-not on face, but in
effect?,nondiscrim means?(6)____
benefit (do consumers benefit, don’t see package) vs. burden
analysis(lost income)(8)____
no market participant exception since state is regulating(2)____
miscellaneous_____________________________________________________(3)____
Question Three Answer Sheet
Genetic Discrimination in Employment Act (50 points)
States-state autonomy (10th Amendmt)-no claim based on argument that
burdens state employmt decisions-regulated along w/private
employers-NLC overturned by Garcia(5 pts)____
state sov-like Printz-compelled to assist enforcemt of fed reg
program-report violations(5)____
state sov-not like Printz-only required to provide info-feds
enforce-reporting is dif(5)____
Employers-beyond power of Congress under Commerce Clause-category
3-local activity(4)____
economic or noneconomic activity?-employment relationship is eco
activity vs discrim(5)____
Could Congress rationally conclude local activity in aggregate has subs
eco effect on IC?(3)____
application to facts-reg all employers w/5 or more-no nexus to IC, in
aggregate, motive(7)____
part of a class of activities or comprehensive regulatory scheme, or
enterprise(3)____
N & P Clause-is it plaintly adapted to IC ends, necy to effective
reg of IC itself, part of gen’l
regulatory scheme(3)____
if Lopez-no jur elem,no findings on IC link, no aggregation, too
attenuated, area of st reg(7)____
Miscellaneous_______________________________________________________(3)____
Question Four Answer Sheet
(Note: 4 points are allocated toward the bottom of the answer sheet to
a DP/EP (Due Process/Equal Protection) analysis. These subjects are not
covered in this set of review questions.)
Tow Truck Licensing Law (48 points)
Dormant Commerce Cl-applies to local ordinances (as well as state
laws)(1 pt)____
Eco Protectionism-illegit purpose?, safety or prevent competition from
out-of-staters?(4)____
Discrimination-facial (all must be licensed) vs in effect (burden on
o-o-s, pass thru, etc.)(5)____
Strict test (if discrim)- legit local purpose? nondiscrim alt
means?(4)____
Balancing test-Burdens-$, licensing even if “passing through” or tow
only a few times(4)____
Benefits - safety (avoid tow truck “racing” accidents like the one that
occurred), more than slight?(4)____
Preemption - valid fed’l
law? commerce power?(3)____
Express preemption/nonpreemption provision - safety - is this
safety?(4)____
If not express - implied? - conflict - can’t comply with both?
conflict in purpose?(4)____
Implied - Occupation of field? Is state or federal interest
dominant? (presume preemption or no preemption?)(4)____
P and I-no discrim ag oos residents, everyone needs license (but if
applies . . .)(4)____
DP/EP-eco rt, can towing law satisfy rational basis?-rationally related
to legit purpose(4)____
Miscellaneous_________________________________________________________(3)____
Question Five Answer
Children’s Toys, Inc. (CTI) will first argue that the Small Parts
Labeling Law is preempted by the provisions of the Federal Toy Safety
Act. The federal law is a valid exercise of the Commerce Clause
because it is a prohibition on shipping toys in interstate commerce
unless they comply with the labeling requirements of the Toy Safety Act
(TSA). The power to regulate interstate commerce itself falls
within category one of the three Lopez categories and is plenary.
As a valid federal law, the TSA can preempt state laws. The Toy
Safety Act does not contain any express preemptive language so it is
necessary to argue that the state law is impliedly preempted by the
TSA. CTI will first argue that there is a conflict between the
state and federal law because the state law undermines the purpose of
the federal law. The federal law is intended to balance safety
against the economic interests of toy manufacturers. In the case
of toys intended for children between 3 and 7, federal law specifically
decided to identify a limited category of risks and those risks did not
include the risks of choking on small parts by children under 3.
An amendment to expand the scope of the federal law to require a
warning label for just such a risk was defeated. Therefore, the
operation of the state law would undermine the delicate balance between
safety and economics that the TSA strikes. In addition, CTI will
argue that there is preemption by occupation of the field. The
field of product labeling of consumer products, including toys, that
are shipped in interstate commerce is chiefly governed by federal
law. The federal law contains detailed provisions on labels to
assure toy safety and Congress specifically rejected any expansion of
those labeling provisions. Therefore, a court should conclude
that the federal government intended to fully occupy the field of toy
safety labeling for toys made for children through the age of 7 and
intended to preclude even state laws that furthered the same safety
purpose as the federal law.
The State of Connecticut will argue that the state law is not preempted
by the TSA. First, it is possible to comply with both the state
and the federal law at the same time since the federally mandated
labels do not preclude a toy from including the additional warning
required by state law. Second, the operation of the state law
does not undermine the federal purpose. The federal purpose is
child safety and the state purpose is also child safety. The
state law just adds an additional layer of safety protection and does
not undermine the federal purpose. In addition, there is nothing to
indicate that the federal government intended to fully occupy the field
of toy safety. The area of child safety is of mutual concern to
both the states and the federal government. A reasonable
presumption is that the federal labeling law establishes a minimum
level of protection and not a maximum level (a floor and not a ceiling)
and that the states are free to impose stricter labeling requirements
for toy safety than the federal government does in the absence of a
clear statement in the federal statute that the federal standards are
intended to be both a floor and a ceiling. Finally, the fact that
Congress did not adopt an amendment that would have expanded the
mandatory labels to include a warning against choking of exactly the
kind the state has adopted does not suggest a different outcome.
It is impossible to know why the federal amendment was defeated and the
fact that the bill was considered indicates that Congress was aware
that the federal law did not regulate every aspect of toy safety,
leaving room for additional regulations by the state.
As an alternative to the preemption argument, CTI will argue that the
state law violates the dormant Commerce Clause. First, CTI will
argue that the stricter test (state must prove it has a legitimate
state purpose and no nondiscriminatory means - means that don't
discriminate against interest commerce - are available to accomplish
that purpose) should apply because the state law discriminates against
out-of-state commerce in its practical effect. The law, like the
North Carolina apple labeling law, has no adverse impact on Connecticut
toy manufacturers, but will adversely effect out-of-state companies by
requiring they add an additional warning label to some toys. As a
law that discriminates, even if it promotes the legitimate purpose of
child safety, the state will still need to show that the state has no
nondiscriminatory alternative means available to protect child
safety. Other means that do not require a change in labeling
exist to protect children such as a campaign by the state to inform
parents about the hazards of choking on small parts.
CTI will
also argue that the state law is an example of economic protectionism
because it was designed to protect Safe Toys, Inc. from out-of-state
competition. Safe Toys, Inc. was a strong supporter of the state
law and the only manufacturer of toys for children between the ages of
three and seven located in Connecticut. Most importantly, Safe Toys
already labels its toys as required under state law so the new law will
not have any adverse impact on Safe Toys but will adversely effect its
out-of-state competitors. Means that are designed to protect the
state's economic interests are illegitimate under the strict test and
therefore the state would fail to satisfy the requirement of having a
legitimate local purpose.
CTI will also argue that even if the balancing test applies, the
burdens of the law on interstate commerce outweigh the safety
benefits. The law imposes additional costs on CTI and other toy
companies that sell their products in Connecticut. That economic
burden is not offset by any safety benefit. The state has not
demonstrated that the warning label requirement it has adopted will
alter the behavior of parents and save the lives of children. While the
state heard testimony that choking on small parts is one of the leading
causes of toy-related deaths in children under age three, it did not
hear any testimony that warning labels reduce the number of such
deaths. Moreover, the state did not learn whether the cause of
the choking deaths was the result of unlabeled toys intended for older
children or toys with a warning label intended for children under
3. It is not sufficient to assert such a safety benefit, the
state must prove that parents pay attention to such labels when buying
toys and it failed to do so.
The state will respond to the dormant Commerce Clause argument by
asserting that the purpose of the law was child safety and not economic
protectionism. Before passing the law the state heard from
medical experts that choking on small parts is one of the leading
causes of toy-related deaths for children under 3. This evidence
makes clear that there is a genuine threat to child safety that the
state responded to by enacting the law. Moreover, the law does
not discriminate against out-of-state commerce. All toy
manufacturers must comply with the law. There is no exemption for
Connecticut companies. Even if the court finds that the law
discriminates in its effect, there is no alternative means available
that would be equally effective. Warning labels are a standard
means to warn consumers of the hazards of a consumer product.
Unlike the North Carolina labeling case, the state law does not require
that a toy company remove any of its current labels, it only requires
that it add one additional label. This is not very burdensome.
Finally, if the court concludes the law does not discriminate against
out-of-state commerce, it should also find that the benefits of the law
outweigh the burdens on interstate commerce. The economic burdens
of an additional label are quite modest as compared to the likelihood
that the additional label will save the lives of some children.
Question Five Answer Sheet
Small Parts Labeling Law (40 points)
preemption-identify
issue(1
pt)____
valid fed'l law?-is law valid under power to regulate interstate
commerce(4)____
express preemption by Fed Toy Safety Act?-does fed’l law expressly
preempt state law?(2)____
conflict-is it impossible to comply with both fed and state law at the
same time?(4)____
conflict in purpose-does the operation of the state law undermine the
federal purpose?(4)____
occupation of the field-did Congress intend to fully occupy the field
and which field?(4)____
dormant commerce clause–identify
issue(1)____
strict test-discrim ag interstate commerce-no discrim on face of law,
but is there
discrim in effect?(4)____
legit state purpose and no nondiscriminatory means are
available(4)
strict test-eco protectionism - was law designed to benefit a local toy
company?(4)____
balancing test - burdens on interstate commerce vs. local benefits
(more than
slight?)(5)____
miscellaneous/special level of
understanding___________________________________(3)____
Question Six Answer Sheet
Q III (excursion train residency discount) (25 points)
Privileges and Immunities Clause of Article IV- individual not
corporation is suing(1 pt)____
discrim ag nonresidents (no discount)?-res vs. nonres or pt time vs
full time residents(4)____
is it a right essential to interstate harmony?- recreational activity-
not income producing(4)____
subst’l reason for discrim- residents contribute to taxes, but so do
all prop’y owners(4)____
degree of discrim subst’ly related to sub’l reason-100 % discrim, but
nonres property tax(4)____
are there less discrim alt means? - e.g. could grant partial discount
to summer residents(4)____
no market participant exception available under
P&I(1)____
miscellaneous_________________________________________________________(3)____
Question Seven Answer Sheet
Question II (Federal Single Sex Educational Opportunity Act)
1) Com Cl- cat 3, local activity, eco/noneco?, could Congress
rationally conclude etc.(4 pts)____
Is education an economic or a noneconomic activity?(4)____
If eco-sub’l effect on IC in aggregate?(4)____
If noneco, Lopez factors, no jur element, no findings, attenuated link,
trad’l st function?(8)____
2) Spending clause-grants to schools on condition-apply 4 part Doe
test-gen’l welfare, unambiguous, rationally related to purpose of
spending, independent const’l bar (EP violation?)(6)____
Question Eight
The farmer can challenge the law as a violation of the dormant Commerce
Clause because it discriminates against out-of-state commerce by
excluding the sale of fruits and vegetables grown in other states from
participation in the Farmer’s Markets. This restriction involves
both discriminatory means as well as impermissible ends because it is
an example of economic protectionism in that it seeks to preclude the
sale of products grown in other states in order to promote the sale of
products grown within the state. As a program that discriminates
against out-of-state commerce, the state must show that the restriction
is designed to advance a legitimate local interest and that there are
no nondiscriminatory alternative means available to advance that
interest. The restriction fails both prongs of the test.
The purpose of the law is the illegitimate one of economic
protectionism and the means, an outright exclusion of products grown
outside the state from participating in the state-sponsored Farmer’s
Markets, are not the only means available to achieve the state's
objective. Instead of banning the sale of out-of-state fruits and
vegetables entirely, the state could allow local farmers to label their
products as locally grown and could promote the sale of such products,
as it is doing, through its publicity campaign that encourages the
buying of local produce through its “Support Your Local Farmer”
campaign. This would encourage the buying of local products without
excluding out-of-state products entirely from the Farmer's Markets.
The State of Midwest would defend its restriction by arguing that the
state is a market participant and not a market regulator. It is
not regulating the fruit and vegetable market. Private sellers of
fruits and vegetables are free to sell products grown everywhere.
The state is only deciding what it wants to sell in the 3 Farmers
Markets that it operates. As a seller of fruits and vegetables,
the state should be permitted to decide what it wants to sell.
This case does not involve a natural resource, international commerce
or downstream activity. The state is not trying to control what
purchasers of fruits and vegetables at its markets do with the products
they buy. It is only seeking to control the goods that it sells
in the market in which it participates (the sale of fruits and
vegetables market). Because the state gets the benefit of the
market participant exception, it is free to discriminate against
out-of-state products in order to protect local farmers.
The farmer challenging the restriction can also claim that his rights
under the Privileges and Immunities Clause of Article IV have been
violated. He will argue that he satisfies the three threshold
requirements because (1) he is a flesh and blood non-resident, (2) who
has been
discriminated against because he is an out-of-state farmer, and (3) he
is
being denied the right to pursue a lawful occupation (selling fruits
and vegetables) by the State of Midwest, thus infringing on one of the
privileges and immunities protected by the clause.
The state will argue in response that the state is not discriminating
based on residency. It is only discriminating based on the place
where fruits and vegetables are grown. If a nonresident of
Midwest owns land in Midwest the nonresident would be able to sell
fruits and vegetables grown on that land at the Farmer’s Markets.
Moreover, a resident of Midwest who owns farmland in Midsouth and grows
produce on that land would not be able to sell the fruits and
vegetables at the Midwest Farmer’s Markets. Therefore the law
does not discriminate based on residency.
The Midsouth farmer will respond to this argument by asserting that the
practical effect of the law is to operate as a discrimination against
out-of-state residents because the vast majority of farmers who own
land in Midwest are residents of Midwest and very few residents of
Midwest own farmland outside of Midwest.
It addition, the state will argue that the right to sell fruits and
vegetables at a market operated by the state is not a privilege and
immunity of state citizenship because it only involves an
exclusion from the state’s own markets and not from private
markets within the state. It is similar to the distinction
between government employment and private employment. The Supreme
Court has found that the right to hold a government job is not one of
the privileges and immunities of state citizenship. Similarly,
the court should find that the right to sell fruits and vegetables at
state-owned markets is not a privilege and immunity of state
citizenship.
If the farmer succeeds in convincing the court to reach the merits of
his privileges and immunities clause claim, the burden will shift to
the state and the state will have to show(1) that it has a substantial
reason for treating nonresidents differently (they are a peculiar
source of the evil the state is trying to address) and (2) that the
degree of discrimination against nonresidents bears a substantial
relationship to the state’s objective. The farmer will argue that
the state cannot satisfy this intermediate scrutiny test because, even
if promoting local farmers is a substantial state interest, the degree
of discrimination (100 % discrimination because out of state farmers
are completely excluded) is not substantially related to the state’s
objective. There are many less discriminatory alternatives that
would promote local farmers while still allowing access by out-of-state
growers. For example, the state could subsidize Midwest farms and
therefore allow them to sell their fruits and vegetables at lower
prices giving them a significant market advantage over produce grown in
other states or the state could both allow local growers to label their
produce as locally grown and heavily promote buying from local farms
while still allowing out-of-state produce to be sold at its Farmer’s
Markets. Both of these alternative means involve a closer fit between
the means and the state's ends and demonstrate that the total ban is
not substantially related to the state's objective.
If the state fails to convince the court that it can satisfy the
standard used under the Privileges and Immunities Clause of Article IV,
it cannot depend on a market participant exception because, unlike the
dormant Commerce Clause, there is no market participant exception to
the Privileges and Immunities Clause.
(NOTE: There is one other minor issue in this question, but it is
beyond that scope of what we have covered thus far. The farmer
could also challenge the law under the 14th Amendment Equal Protection
Clause because it discriminates based on the location where the fruits
and vegetables are grown and prefers locally grown produce over produce
grown outside the state. This form of discrimination is not based
on a suspect classification and would only be subject to a rational
basis review and the state would almost certainly be able to show that
its restriction is rationally related to a legitimate state
interest. Therefore, the equal protection challenge would fail.)